Brazen & cynical…Poul Thomsen, Greece And IMF Cynicism.

Daniel Munevar

For the casual reader, Poul Thomsen’s recent piece on the role of the IMF in the bailout review negotiations taking place between Greece and the Troika would seem balanced and reasonable. At the end of the day, as he has argued elsewhere, the numbers simply need to add up. For that, there is a trade-off between the “ambition of the reforms” Greece needs to impose and the amount of debt relief that can be granted by its European partners. Put bluntly, more austerity implies less debt relief and vice versa.

Thomsen argues that given the contentious character of the negotiations the IMF is simply there as a friendly companion that supports both its Greek and European partners to make the tough decisions required to develop a program that adds up. However, for someone who is more familiar with the role that the IMF in general, and Thomsen in particular, has played in putting Greece in the precarious situation in which it finds itself today, his piece can only be defined as brazen and cynical.

In order to unpack Thomsen’s argument, we need to go by parts:

Ultimately a program must add up: the combination of reforms plus debt relief must give us and the international community reasonable assurances that by the end of Greece’s next program, after almost a decade of dependence on European and IMF assistance, Greece will finally be able to stand on its own”

It’s interesting that Thomsen makes this argument now, when in 2010 he was directly responsible for the structure of the initial bailout agreement for Greece: one that did not include debt relief. Back then, even though several IMF departments had recommended a debt restructuring, Thomsen and the European Department “believed a haircut should not even be considered at this juncture.” When the IMF Board met in May 2010 to approve the bailout package for Greece, Thomsen defended the program even though it was impossible to certify that it would ensure debt sustainability. As this was against the IMF’s lending policies, the board also approved a change in its rules so as to allow loans that do not ensure debt sustainability, as long as there is a “high risk of international systemic spillover effects.”

In simple terms, a loan beyond the economic capacity of a country to pay it back could be granted if it could help to avoid panic in international financial markets. Thus, from the start, both Thomsen and the IMF were aware that Greece was being granted a loan that it couldn’t be expected to pay back, and therefore had no hope of eventually being “able to stand on its own”.

This said, no amount of pension reforms will make Greece’s debt sustainable without debt relief, and no amount of debt relief will make Greece’s pension system sustainable without pension reforms. Both need to come about.

Once the original program had gone off track in 2012, debt restructuring became unavoidable. At this point, foreign creditors had reduced their exposure towards Greece by about €90bn thanks to the funding provided by the first bailout. Furthermore, once debt restructuring was completed, Greek banks were fully protected from the losses derived from their holdings of government debt. However, domestic pension funds were not. As a result of the 2012 debt restructuring, pension funds lost an estimated €14.5bn (see here). Thus, the delayed debt relief provided to Greece came precisely at the expense of the pension system of the country.

There is no doubt that both Greece and its European partners will face politically difficult decisions in the coming months to arrive at a program that is viable—one that adds up. Such difficult decisions cannot be “kicked down the road” through unrealistic assumptions.

It is interesting that Thomsen highlights the role of unrealistic assumptions in kicking the can down the road: this is exactly what the IMF has done over the last five years. For example, the first adjustment program, personally approved by Thomsen, was based on the assumption that Greece was going to be able to achieve and sustain a primary fiscal surplus of 6% of GDP in the medium term. It was clearly absurd to expect that any country could achieve this type of fiscal adjustment but, in order for the numbers to add up, this was the inevitable result of excluding debt relief. Furthermore, despite the problems associated with this approach, the IMF has continued to base its assessments on it: the second adjustment program assumed a medium term target of primary surplus of 4.5%, whereas the third program assumes one of 3.5% for the next several decades. On the face of historical evidence, which shows no country even close to achieving such a large and sustained adjustment, it begs the question of why the IMF continues to endorse this futile exercise of can-kicking.

Thus, assuming that Greece can simply grow out of its debt problem without debt relief—by rapidly transitioning from the lowest to the highest productivity growth within the euro zone—is not credible.


As it happens, this was exactly the basic assumption underlying the growth projections for Greece for the first two programs. In theory, full implementation of the structural reforms would allow the country to “go from having the lowest average TFP growth in the euro area since it joined the EU in 1981 to having among the highest TFP growth, and that it would go to the highest labor force participation rates and to German employment rates”. It’s important to highlight that research conducted by the IMF itself has shown that some of the structural reforms which the organization has emphasized over the last decades, and quarreled about with the Greek government such as labor market reform, have no or negative impact upon TFP and growth.

Why the focus on pension reforms? Despite the pension reforms of 2010 and 2012, Greece’s pension system remains unaffordably generous.

Let’s leave aside for a moment the fact that a system in which 45% of the pensioners in the country live below the poverty line can hardly be defined as generous. Instead, let’s just focus on the macroeconomic impact of austerity on the sustainability of the pension system. First, expenditure on pensions by the Greek government was reduced from €21.7bn to €17.1bn between 2011 and 2014 – a cut of 21%. Even so, spending on pensions as a share of GDP has not gone down simply because the pace of economic contraction has been even faster than that of the cuts.

Second, the rapid growth of unemployment caused by the crisis has decimated pension contributions. Because nearly 1m have disappeared from the labor force, these have declined from €22bn in 2009 to €16bn in 2016. Third, lower contributions can also be attributed to the cuts in wages that are integral to the strategy of internal devaluation. For example, in the case of the biggest pension fund, the average salary of its members dropped from €13300 in 2009 to €10300 in 2014. Thus, even though an argument can be made regarding the need to address the institutional failures of the Greek pension system, it is important for the IMF to recognize the negative impact of its policies on the system’s sustainability.

But can’t Greece protect pensioners by cutting somewhere else or increasing tax rates? There is some scope for those measures, but it is very limited. Most other spending has already been cut to the bone in an effort to protect pensions and social payments… Greece will need to take measures in the order of some 4-5 percent of GDP. We cannot see how Greece can do so without major savings on pensions.”

The reason why other spending has already been cut to the bone is that Greece has undertaken the largest fiscal adjustment in the developed world: between 2009 and 2014, the cyclically adjusted primary balance showed an improvement of 19% of GDP. In the Eurozone, the closest country in terms of fiscal adjustment over the same period is Ireland with an adjustment of 10% of GDP. Furthermore, as a result of this massive adjustment, GDP contracted by an almost equal amount, making the fiscal effort effectively self-defeating. Thus, to demand further adjustments when the country is already running one of the highest cyclically adjusted primary surpluses in the developed world, is effectively to double down on what we already know is a failed strategy.

Could a primary surplus target well below 3½ percent of GDP make the necessary pension reform less demanding? Perhaps, but that would necessitate more debt relief. This is understandably controversial among Greece’s European partners, in part because several of them are required to run similarly high surpluses to preserve debt sustainability, and in part because some of the countries that would be in effect paying for debt relief to Greece are poorer than Greece, paying much less generous pensions to their own people.”

It is a shame that Thomsen didn’t have the same concerns regarding international fairness and solidarity back in 2010, as he seems to have in 2016. Then, he had no problem in supporting a program that, as a former IMF Executive Director has pointed out, pooled IMF and European resources to save French and German banks with significant exposure to Greece. Did he worry then about those poor countries that were being ask to lend €110bn to Greece in order to rescue French/German banks? Was he concerned about the fact that it was unlikely that those poor countries would ever see their money back? Perhaps. What we do know is that less than a month ago, the IMF changed its lending policies again in order to eliminate the systemic risk clause that allowed approval of the different adjustment programs for Greece. When doing so, the IMF recognized that the systemic exemption that allowed it to lend beyond what could be economically justified “delayed the restoration of debt sustainability, impaired the prospects of success for the country’s economic policy program, and eroded safeguards for IMF resources.” Even though this is the right thing to do, the effects of the IMF flip-flopping will linger on: the bailed out French and German bankers will get to enjoy their golden retirements, Greek pensioners will continue to see their pensions slashed and creditors from those poor countries will probably never see their money back.

The IMF does not want Greece to implement draconian fiscal adjustment in an already severely depressed economy. In fact, we have time and again been the ones arguing for a fiscal adjustment path that is more supportive of recovery in the near term and more realistic in the medium term.

It’s incredible, to say the least, for Thomsen to claim that the IMF has been in favor of a more supportive path to fiscal adjustment when that was never the case, at least until July 2015. Since 2010, the Fund’s official position has been that debt sustainability in Greece could be ensured as long as the government achieved the program’s fiscal targets, regardless of how realistic these were. The first time that the IMF publicly acknowledged the problems with the adjustment program came as a result of the leak, on July 3 2015, of a debt sustainability analysis prepared by the organization itself. In it, the IMF conceded the over-optimistic nature of the assumptions used in previous assessments and pointed out that debt sustainability in Greece could only be achieved through further relief. Given the paper’s sensitive political nature, the European members actively tried to block its official publication but pressure by the US and others ensured it was released to the public. So one is left wondering when and where exactly the IMF has argued in favor of a more realistic fiscal adjustment in the specific case of Greece.

https://www.socialeurope.eu/2016/02/poul-thomsen-greece-and-imf-cynicism/

 

About Daniel Munevar

Daniel Munevar is a former advisor to Yanis Varoufakis. In the past he worked as fiscal advisor to the Ministry of Finance of Colombia and special advisor on Foreign Direct Investment for the Ministry of Foreign Affairs of Ecuador. He has a Masters in Public Affairs from the LBJ School at the University of Texas at Austin.

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s